Skip to content

Commit

Permalink
[Sraffa] Revised notes on Ch. 3 of PCMC
Browse files Browse the repository at this point in the history
  • Loading branch information
pqnelson committed Feb 28, 2016
1 parent e0cdb60 commit edadab4
Showing 1 changed file with 50 additions and 30 deletions.
80 changes: 50 additions & 30 deletions sraffa/pcmc.org
Original file line number Diff line number Diff line change
Expand Up @@ -370,12 +370,12 @@ reasoning, without manipulating a model at hand. Proceed /very slowly!/
- We now give the wage /w/ successive values ranging from 1 to 0: these
represent fractions of the national income
(compare \sect[[section_10][10]] and \sect[[section_12][12]]).
- The object: observe the effect of changes in the wage on rate of
profits, and on the prices of individual commodities...on the
assumption the methods of production remain unchanged.
- Objective: determine how changes in the wage affects the rate of
profits, and the prices of individual commodities...assuming the
methods of production remain unchanged.
*** 14. Values when whole National Income goes to Wages
#+NAME: section_14
- When we make /w/ equal to 1, the whole national income goes to wages
- When we make /w/ = 1, the whole national income goes to wages
and /r/ is eliminated.
- We thus revert to the systems of equations we /began/ with! The
difference being the quantities of labor are now shown explicitly
Expand All @@ -386,17 +386,36 @@ reasoning, without manipulating a model at hand. Proceed /very slowly!/
produce them. (See [[appendix_a][Appendix "On Sub-Systems"]])
- Sraffa asserts "at no other wage-level do values follow a simple
rule".
- This is fairly cryptic. Does he mean values will not
be in proportion to the quantity of labor which directly and
indirectly produce the commodities? Or does he mean something else?
- Question: This is fairly cryptic. Does he mean values will not be in
proportion to the quantity of labor which directly and indirectly
produce the commodities? Or does he mean something else?
- Answer: What Sraffa means, I believe, is that at no other wage level
do we recover the first sort of model we discussed...instead we
recover a system where the "relative values of commodities" are not
in direct proportion to their labor costs.
- *Remark.* It seems this proposition has some bearing on the labor
theory of value, although not in the "obvious way"...
*** 15. Variety in the proportions of labor to Means of Production
#+NAME: section_15
- Lets consider, starting from the situation where the whole national
income goes to labor, we imagine wages are reduced: a rate of profits
- Consider the situation when the wages are reduced (i.e., we don't
allocate the national product as wage): a rate of profits
will emerge.
- The key (to the movement of relative prices consequent upon a change in
the wage) lies in the inequality of the proportions in which labor and
the means of production are used in the various industries.
- How do "relative prices" react to changes in wage?
- The key lies in the inequality of the proportions in which labor and
the means of production are used in the various industries.
- *Remark.* This phrasing seems ambiguous to me. What exactly is the
"proportion" Sraffa speaks of? Isn't it apples and oranges? Or does he
mean the ratio of "the value of the means of production" to the wage?

It seems, based on reading further text, Sraffa refers to the ratio
of the "value of the means of production" to the wage...well, I
/think/ he means wage (or else it could be the "value of the labor").

Sraffa is motivating his "Standard commodity" (the subject of the
next chapter!). The ratio, for the moment, is of values...but later
we will see it doesn't matter if we use values or actual
commodities. Yes it is "apples and oranges", but Sraffa's genius
works this out!
- If the proportion were the same in all industries, no price-changes
could ensue regardless of any diversity of the commodity-composition
of the means of production in different industries.
Expand All @@ -421,15 +440,16 @@ reasoning, without manipulating a model at hand. Proceed /very slowly!/
when there is inequality of "proportions".
- Suppose prices /did/ remain unchanged when the wage was reduced and a
rate of profits emerged.
- Since in any one industry what was saved through the wage-reduction
would depend on the number of men employed---while what was necessary
for paying profits at a uniform rate would depend on the aggregate
value of the means of production used---industries with a
sufficiently low proportion of labor to means of production would
have a deficit...while industries with a sufficiently high
- Since in any one industry

1. what was saved through the wage-reduction would depend on the number of men employed, while
2. what was necessary for paying profits at a uniform rate would depend on the aggregate value of the means of production used,

Industries with a sufficiently low proportion of labor to means of
production would have a deficit...while industries with a sufficiently high
proportion would have a *surplus*, on their payments for wages and profits.
- Nothing is assumed at the moment as to what rate of profits
correspond to what wage reduction; all we require at this stage is
correspond to what wage reduction. All we require at this stage is
there should be a uniform wage and a uniform rate of profits
throughout the system.
*** 17. A Watershed Proportion
Expand Down Expand Up @@ -537,15 +557,12 @@ reasoning, without manipulating a model at hand. Proceed /very slowly!/
- It will be convenient to replace the "proportion" (quantity of labor
to means of production) with one of the corresponding "pure" ratios
between homogeneous quantities.

There are two such ratios:
1. the quantity-ratio of direct to indirect labor employed; and
2. the value-ratio of net product to means of production.

These two ratios coincide when the value-ratio is calculated at the
values for /w/ = 1.

Sraffa uses the latter ratio here.
- There are two such ratios:
1. the *quantity-ratio* of direct to indirect labor employed; and
2. the *value-ratio* of net product to means of production.
- These two ratios coincide when the value-ratio is calculated at the
values for /w/ = 1.
- Sraffa uses the latter ratio here.
- The rate of profits is uniform in all industries (and depends only on
the wage), the value-ratio of the net product to the means of
production is in general different for each industry and mainly
Expand All @@ -556,9 +573,9 @@ reasoning, without manipulating a model at hand. Proceed /very slowly!/
the general rate of profits /r/. At this level the "value ratios" of
all industries are equal, regardless of how different the "value
ratios" may have been at other wage-levels.
- The only "value-ratio" which can be invariant to changes in wage (and
- The only "value-ratio" which /can/ be invariant to changes in wage (and
thus capable of being "recurrent" in the sense defined in \sect[[section_21][21]])
is the one that is equal to the rate of profits corresponding with
is the one equal to the rate of profits corresponding with
zero wage. And /that/ is the "balancing" ratio.
- *Definition.* The "*Maximum Rate of Profits*" is the rate of profits
as it would be if the whole national income went to profits, and we
Expand Down Expand Up @@ -587,6 +604,9 @@ reasoning, without manipulating a model at hand. Proceed /very slowly!/
commodities) as anything else could. *BUT* we should know any such
fluctuations would originate in the peculiarities of the production
of the compared commodity...the change would *not* occur on its own.

- *Remark.* What Sraffa suggests, in modern terms, would be that a
[[https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Num%C3%A9raire][Numeraire]] exists.
*** 24. The perfect Composite Commodity
#+NAME: section_24
- It's doubtful any single commodity posses the desired properties.
Expand Down

0 comments on commit edadab4

Please sign in to comment.